<C1A4C3A5C0DAB7E D313028B1E8C0B1C8F1292E687770>

Similar documents
#Ȳ¿ë¼®

Á¶´öÈñ_0304_final.hwp

hwp

Vol.259 C O N T E N T S M O N T H L Y P U B L I C F I N A N C E F O R U M

DBPIA-NURIMEDIA

DBPIA-NURIMEDIA

DBPIA-NURIMEDIA

2



09김정식.PDF

부문별 에너지원 수요의 변동특성 및 공통변동에 미치는 거시적 요인들의 영향력 분석


에너지경제연구 제13권 제1호

Microsoft PowerPoint - Freebairn, John_ppt


06_À̼º»ó_0929

Vol.257 C O N T E N T S M O N T H L Y P U B L I C F I N A N C E F O R U M

大学4年生の正社員内定要因に関する実証分析

04-다시_고속철도61~80p

<28BCF6BDC D B0E6B1E2B5B520C1F6BFAABAB020BFA9BCBAC0CFC0DAB8AE20C1A4C3A520C3DFC1F8C0FCB7AB5FC3D6C1BE E E687770>

07_À±¿ø±æ3ÀüºÎ¼öÁ¤

¹ýÁ¶ 12¿ù ¼öÁ¤.PDF

Journal of Educational Innovation Research 2017, Vol. 27, No. 2, pp DOI: : Researc

182 동북아역사논총 42호 금융정책이 조선에 어떤 영향을 미쳤는지를 살펴보고자 한다. 일제 대외금융 정책의 기본원칙은 각 식민지와 점령지마다 별도의 발권은행을 수립하여 일본 은행권이 아닌 각 지역 통화를 발행케 한 점에 있다. 이들 통화는 일본은행권 과 等 價 로 연

... 수시연구 국가물류비산정및추이분석 Korean Macroeconomic Logistics Costs in 권혁구ㆍ서상범...

<313120B9DABFB5B1B82E687770>


ÀÌÁÖÈñ.hwp

- 2 -

<3136C1FD31C8A320C5EBC7D52E687770>

한국성인에서초기황반변성질환과 연관된위험요인연구

Output file

6 영상기술연구 실감하지 못했을지도 모른다. 하지만 그 이외의 지역에서 3D 영화를 관람하기란 그리 쉬운 일이 아니다. 영화 <아바타> 이후, 티켓 파워에 민감한 국내 대형 극장 체인들이 2D 상영관을 3D 상영관으로 점차적으로 교체하는 추세이긴 하지만, 아직까지는 관

2011´ëÇпø2µµ 24p_0628

歯1.PDF

03이경미(237~248)ok

<3136C1FD31C8A35FC3D6BCBAC8A3BFDC5F706466BAAFC8AFBFE4C3BB2E687770>

에너지경제연구 제14권 제1호

에너지경제연구제 16 권제 1 호 Korean Energy Economic Review Volume 16, Number 1, March 2017 : pp. 35~55 학술 전력시장가격에대한역사적요인분해 * 35

,,,.,,,, (, 2013).,.,, (,, 2011). (, 2007;, 2008), (, 2005;,, 2007).,, (,, 2010;, 2010), (2012),,,.. (, 2011:,, 2012). (2007) 26%., (,,, 2011;, 2006;

한국 출산력의 저하 요인에 관한 연구

11¹Ú´ö±Ô

에너지경제연구 Korean Energy Economic Review Volume 17, Number 2, September 2018 : pp. 1~29 정책 용도별특성을고려한도시가스수요함수의 추정 :, ARDL,,, C4, Q4-1 -

<BCF6BDC D31385FB0EDBCD3B5B5B7CEC8DEB0D4C5B8BFEEB5B5C0D4B1B8BBF3BFACB1B85FB1C7BFB5C0CE2E687770>

20, 41..,..,.,.,....,.,, (relevant).,.,..??.,

한국체육학회지.hwp

Microsoft PowerPoint - ch03ysk2012.ppt [호환 모드]


이용석 박환용 - 베이비부머의 특성에 따른 주택유형 선택 변화 연구.hwp

레이아웃 1

①국문지리학회지-주성재-OK


05_±è½Ã¿Ł¿Ü_1130

아니라 일본 지리지, 수로지 5, 지도 6 등을 함께 검토해야 하지만 여기서는 근대기 일본이 편찬한 조선 지리지와 부속지도만으로 연구대상을 한정하 기로 한다. Ⅱ. 1876~1905년 울릉도 독도 서술의 추이 1. 울릉도 독도 호칭의 혼란과 지도상의 불일치 일본이 조선

DBPIA-NURIMEDIA

11¹ÚÇý·É

12È«±â¼±¿Ü339~370

<C7F6B4EBBACFC7D1BFACB1B B1C72033C8A E687770>

IDP www idp or kr IDP 정책연구 한국경제의구조적문제와개혁방향 민주정책연구원 The Institute for Democracy and Policies

WHO 의새로운국제장애분류 (ICF) 에대한이해와기능적장애개념의필요성 ( 황수경 ) ꌙ 127 노동정책연구 제 4 권제 2 호 pp.127~148 c 한국노동연구원 WHO 의새로운국제장애분류 (ICF) 에대한이해와기능적장애개념의필요성황수경 *, (disabi

歯주5일본문.PDF

433대지05박창용

<C0C7B7CAC0C720BBE7C8B8C0FB20B1E2B4C9B0FA20BAAFC8AD5FC0CCC7F6BCDB2E687770>

44-3대지.08류주현c

:,,.,. 456, 253 ( 89, 164 ), 203 ( 44, 159 ). Cronbach α= ,.,,..,,,.,. :,, ( )

232 도시행정학보 제25집 제4호 I. 서 론 1. 연구의 배경 및 목적 사회가 다원화될수록 다양성과 복합성의 요소는 증가하게 된다. 도시의 발달은 사회의 다원 화와 밀접하게 관련되어 있기 때문에 현대화된 도시는 경제, 사회, 정치 등이 복합적으로 연 계되어 있어 특

歯kjmh2004v13n1.PDF

pdf 16..

< C7CFB9DDB1E22028C6EDC1FD292E687770>

민속지_이건욱T 최종


2 동북아역사논총 50호 구권협정으로 해결됐다 는 일본 정부의 주장에 대해, 일본군 위안부 문제는 일 본 정부 군 등 국가권력이 관여한 반인도적 불법행위이므로 한일청구권협정 에 의해 해결된 것으로 볼 수 없다 는 공식 입장을 밝혔다. 또한 2011년 8월 헌 법재판소는

Journal of Educational Innovation Research 2017, Vol. 27, No. 1, pp DOI: NCS : G * The Analy

<BFACB1B85F D333528C0CCC3B6BCB1295FC3D6C1BEC8AEC1A45FC0CEBCE2BFEB E687770>

노동경제논집 38권 4호 (전체).hwp

제 2 장 골프장의 경영

서론 34 2

12Á¶±ÔÈŁ

<C0CEBCE2BFEB5FBFACB1B85F D32322D3528BAAFBCF6C1A4295F FBCF6C1A42E687770>

09È«¼®¿µ 5~152s

歯kjmh2004v13n1.PDF

<BFACBCBCC0C7BBE7C7D E687770>

DBPIA-NURIMEDIA

01이정훈(113~127)ok

¨ë Áö¸®ÇÐȸÁö-¼Û°æ¾ðOK

1. 서론 1-1 연구 배경과 목적 1-2 연구 방법과 범위 2. 클라우드 게임 서비스 2-1 클라우드 게임 서비스의 정의 2-2 클라우드 게임 서비스의 특징 2-3 클라우드 게임 서비스의 시장 현황 2-4 클라우드 게임 서비스 사례 연구 2-5 클라우드 게임 서비스에

서론

에너지경제연구 Korean Energy Economic Review Volume 11, Number 2, September 2012 : pp. 1~26 실물옵션을이용한해상풍력실증단지 사업의경제성평가 1

216 동북아역사논총 41호 인과 경계공간은 설 자리를 잃고 배제되고 말았다. 본고에서는 근세 대마도에 대한 한국과 일본의 인식을 주로 영토와 경계인 식을 중심으로 고찰하고자 한다. 이 시기 대마도에 대한 한일 양국의 인식을 살펴볼 때는 근대 국민국가적 관점에서 탈피할

±³º¸¸®¾óÄÚ

02김헌수(51-72.hwp

?? 1990년대 중반부터 일부 지방에서 자체적인 정책 혁신 을 통해 시도된 대학생촌관 정책은 그 효과에 비자발적 확산 + 대한 긍정적 평가에 힘입어 조금씩 다른 지역으로 수평적 확산이 이루어졌다. 이? + 지방 A 지방 B 비자발적 확산 중앙 중앙정부 정부 비자발적

에너지경제연구제 16 권제 1 호 Korean Energy Economic Review Volume 16, Number 1, March 2017 : pp. 95~118 학술 탄소은행제의가정용전력수요절감효과 분석 1) 2) 3) * ** *** 95

<B3EDB9AEC1FD5F3235C1FD2E687770>

에너지경제연구 Korean Energy Economic Review Volume 9, Number 2, September 2010 : pp. 1~18 가격비대칭성검정모형민감도분석 1

중국 상장회사의 경영지배구조에 관한 연구

2 - ABSTRACT The object of this study is to investigate the practical effects of Senior Employment Project, implemented by government as a part of sen

02신현화

07_Àü¼ºÅÂ_0922

Transcription:

ⅰ 목차 Ⅰ. INTRODUCTION 3 1. Kuznets in Korea 3 2. The overview of Korean economy 5 Ⅱ. REVIEW OF THE LITERATURE 10 Ⅲ. METHODOLOGY AND DATA 14 Ⅳ. RESULTS 19 Ⅴ. DISCUSSION 25 Reference 27 Summary 30

ⅱ 표목차 Table 1. The tendency of labor distribution in Korea manufacturing sector (1000) 8 Table 2. A descriptive statistics of firms between 1993-2003 18

ⅲ 그림목차 Fig. 1. The augmented Kuznets Curve 4 Fig. 2. GDP per Capital 7 Fig. 3. Pay Inequality of Korean Manufacturing. 1993-2003 19 Fig. 4. The Contribution of Firm sizes to Pay Inequality in Korea 21 Fig. 5. The Contribution of Individual locations to Pay Inequality in Korea 22 Fig. 6. The Evolution of Inequality across Manufacturing Sectors 23

요약 1 요약 1. 연구의목적및필요성 1955년쿠즈네츠가발표한학설에의하면경제성장과 pay inequality의관계는일정한관계가있다. 물론경제성장을위해서는 inequality의어느부분은감수를해야하지만과거선진국의경제발전양상과 inequality의흐름을비교해볼때한국은과거와다른양상을뛰고있다. 즉, 쿠즈네츠의가설에의하면경제성장초기에는 inequality가높아지다가어느정도후에는점차감소를하게된다. 그러나다시일정한시간이지나면증가하게되는경향이있는데일본, 미국, 영국등많은선진국들이이런흐름의과정을거쳐왔다. 그러나한국은 1996년말외환위기를겪으면서 inequality가낮아지기도전에다시높아지는양상을보였는데이는경제성장에따라자연스럽게형성된것이아니라외환위기이후선진국의기준에적합하도록금융및제도적개편이진행되다보니 inequality가높아진것이다. 자연스러운 inequality의변화가아니라외부적인영향에의한변화라면사회적수준이나경제적능력은아직선진국이아닌데경제시스템만그기준에맞게개편된것이므로그것에따른부작용이생성될수있다. 따라서본연구에서는실제 inequality가어떤양상으로 90년대이후진행되었는지그것이경제성장흐름과어떻게관계되었는지, 어느분야및어느지역에서진행되었는지를살펴보고시사점을찾고자한다. 2. 주요연구내용 기존에불균형정도를측정하는인덱스로는 Gini coefficient등여러가지방법이있지만, 본연구는 University of Texas at Austin에서현재까지

요약 2 활발하게연구중인 Theil s T statistic을가지고불균형정도를측정하려고한다. 기존문헌에서는국가별또는개인별불균형정도를측정하였지만본연구는 plant 개념에적용시켜한국제조기업들의불균형정도는기업의 size별, 지역별, 연령및기타특성으로분류하여비교하고자한다. 지역별불균형정도를측정하는방법은많이있지만, 본연구의특징은 index화시켜서직접적인비교가가능하고불균형정도를도표화시켜서한눈에분석할수있다. Theil's T statistic은이미활발한연구가진행중인 inequality 분석방법이며아직까지국내제조업에이방법을적용시켜서분석한사례는없으며이것을쿠즈네츠의가설과관련시켜서비교연구한경우는아직없다. 따라서본연구는그분석방법적용및 90년대이후경제개편을추구한한국산업분석에있어서시사점이크다. 따라서본연구는 1993년부터 2003년의광공업통계데이터를이용하여 inequality를측정하고그것과경제성장및혁신에미치는영향을분석하고자한다. 3. 결론또는정책적시사점 많은선진국의사례에서우리는쿠즈네츠가설에따라경제성장에따른 inequality의변화를볼수있다. 그러나본연구의분석결과한국은경제수준은선진국에비해부족한반면 inequality의변화추이는이미일본, 미국, 영국등과같은흐름을보이고있다. 이는 90년대외환위기이후구조적개편을거치면서선진국의기준에맞추다보니불균형정도가심해졌다고판단할수있으며이에따라본연구는이런현상을기업규모별, 지역별, 산업별로분석하여그원인을찾고그에따른정책적시사점을찾고자한다.

Ⅰ. INTRODUCTION 3 Ⅰ. INTRODUCTION 1. Kuznets in Korea Since Kuznets posited his now famous curve in 1955, the relationship between inequality and economic growth has troubled economists and social scientists. Normative questions about social equity aside, whether inequality and growth are correlated and in which direction, if any, causation flows have far-reaching implications for economic and social policy that cannot be ignored. `Is inequality an unfortunate but necessary ingredient for growth, or might equality and growth be compatible or, perhaps, even complementary? Such questions are symptomatic of a broader debate regarding the existence of a tradeoff between innovation and equality in general Okun(1975). This paper addresses these questions by examining the relationship between inequality and growth in Korea, and how that relationship has been affected by the structural economic reforms of the past years. Simon Kuznets hypothesized that the relationship between growth and inequality changes based on a country s development or degree of industrialization. In the initial phase of development, income diverges as the rural population migrates to the more unequal, higher wage urban industrial centers. As the urban proletariat matures, however, political institutions are created that increase lower-wage workers income shares and inequality decreases as industrialization deepens Kuznets(1955). For a given level of income(or industrialization), then, the relationship is assumed to be stable negative for most countries currently on the downward-sloping portion of the curve.

Ⅰ. INTRODUCTION 4 Although Kuznets hypothesized the effect of growth(or development) on inequality, later literature reversed this causal relationship. Empirical work seeking to confirm or reject Kuznets hypothesis has proliferated in recent years, using both pooled and panel data in attempt to shed light on the relationship across countries and time. Surveying twenty-three different studies, Benabou(1996) concluded that initial inequality is detrimental to long-run growth. Fig. 1. The augmented Kuznets Curve Recent work has found that a few rich countries specializing in high-wage, advanced capital goods have experienced a post-kuznets rise in inequality. While most developing and industrialized countries are found on the downward portion of Kuznets inverted U, inequality has been rising with increased income levels in highincome countries like Japan, the United States, and the United Kingdom.6 Conceição and Galbraith (2001) postulate that Kuznets original formulation might apply only as long as countries produce principally consumer goods, and might break down as industrial activity shifts into monopolistic, advanced technology goods for the world market. In that case, the richest and most advanced industrial

Ⅰ. INTRODUCTION 5 economies producing capital goods for export would be found on an augmented Kuznets Curve with an upward-sloping tail for such countries, as shown in Fig. 1. Away from the augmented curve s peak and trough, however, the relationship between growth and inequality is presumed to be a more or less stable function of income level. The present paper adds a new dimension to this research by showing that the relationship between growth and inequality may change, as it does in the case of Korea, as a result of structural reform. Although Korea s income level doesn t change appreciably during the final decades of the 20th century, data on manufacturing pay inequality show that the stable, negative relationship between growth and inequality predicted by Kuznets reverses at the peak of the reform period, thrusting Korea into a small group of otherwise wealthy and highly industrialized countries for whom inequality rises with economic growth. After a brief review of the reforms undertaken during Korea s finical crisis period, we will examine the evidence for this change and mechanisms by which it may have taken place. We conclude with implications and avenues for further research on the topic. 2. The overview of Korean economy As it is well-known, Korea in recent decades has experienced a dramatic economic development. From being one of the poorest countries in the 1960s, it became a member of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development(OECD) in 1996. The economy has made remarkable progress since the early 1960s, with

Ⅰ. INTRODUCTION 6 GNP growth averaging 7.8% per annum between 1961 and 2000. In relatively short time period, the country was transformed swiftly from a poor traditional agricultural society to a modern industrial state. Comprehensive investment programs in technology and human capital made the manufacturing sector the engine of economic growth driven by an outward-looking, government-led development strategy pursued from the early 1960s. The national government intervened extensively in resource allocation, targeting industries to be promoted and provided necessary incentives for development and progress. Many researches including Amsden (1989) and World Bank (1993) chose to study the Korean case as one that could serve as a model for development for other developing countries and the Korean economy was thought to be strong. However the Korean won dropped in value by 50 percent between the end of December 1996 and the end of December 1997. Korea experienced a financial crisis in the mid 1997. The request by the Korean government for a three-year stand-by credit from the IMF amounting to about $21 billion was approved on December 5, 1997 1). The economic crisis in 1997 1998 after three decades of unprecedented economic growth was evident. The outstanding external debt reached US$159 billion in December 1997, the real GDP growth rate declined by 7% and the unemployment rate exceeded 8% in early 1998 from being less than 3% in the early to the mid-1990s. The Fig. 2 shows, despite the economic crisis, the remarkable economic growth of Korea during period (1993-2003) under the consideration in this paper. Per capita income has increased from 1) For details of the IMF program, see IMF (1997). For discussions directed to the effectiveness of the IMF program, see Feldstein (1998) and Fischer (1998).

Ⅰ. INTRODUCTION 7 $8,177 in 1993 to $12,720 in 2003 2). This rapid change gives an extraordinary chance to examine the relationship between economic growth and income distribution and income mobility in Korea. Fig. 2. GDP per Capital Although the Korean economy severely suffered from the Asian financial crisis, it was known for its rapid recovery from the crisis (Yoshitomi and ADB staff, 2003; Koo and Kiser, 2001). However, one can expect that the impact of crisis on firms would differ by various firms characteristics. The industrial policies for firms with different-sized classes changed dramatically, in the post-crisis period. As a result of the recovery policy, large scale enterprises (LSE) succeeded in necessary downsizing in the immediate aftermath of the financial crisis and grew rapidly in the post-crisis period, especially in the export market. On the other hand, small and medium enterprises(sme) were still suffering from the effects of the recession and, in particular, in the domestic market (Oh et al. 2005). Consequently, pay inequality increased over the entire industry and differences with respect to locations and industries were distinguished. Therefore, the relationship between the inequality and industry 2) Source: the Bank of Korea

Ⅰ. INTRODUCTION 8 growth is addressed in the current study. This paper examines pay structure and pay inequality in Korea manufacturing sector using Theil s T statistic between 1993 and 2003. This paper examines pay structure and pay inequality in Korea manufacturing sector using Theil s T statistic between 1993 and 2003. As shown table 1, manufacturing has one of the big partials of Korea industry. The data set is derived from the Annual Reporting on Mining and Manufacturing Survey in Korea and consists of five or more employees in 580 manufacturing industries at the KSIC (Korean Standard Industrial Classification) five-digit level. Table 1. The tendency of labor distribution in Korea manufacturing sector(1000) 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 Total labor 12,245 12,583 13,634 14,006 13,470 12,416 12,920 13,604 14,109 14,608 14,729 Force in 1000 Manufacturing in 1000 (%) 3,884 (31.7) 3,695 (29.4) 3,708 (27.2) 3,748 (26.8) 3,312 (24.6) 2,986 (24.1) 3,170 (24.5) 3,333 (24.5) 3,415 (24.2) 3,392 (23.2) 3,411 (23.2) Mining (%) 51,788 43,589 39,748 35,806 29,888 23,962 21,971 21,406 20,895 20,405 20,537 (1.3) (1.2) (1.1) (1.0) (0.9) (0.8) (0.7) (0.6) (0.6) (0.6) (0.6) Hence we can investigate the location, size, diversification, R&D, export and business sectors of the firm in pay inequality. Also we evaluate how the Asian financial crisis and policies for recovery on pay inequality. This paper studies the change of pay structure and inequality from a comparative perspective. First of all, this paper looks the tendency of pay inequality with economic growth between 1993 and 2003. Second, we divide business sectors, locations and firm size etc, al. then find difference and characteristic. Finally, we compare the analyzed inequality distribution with economic growth, locate Korea's position according to Kuznet's theory and obtain the

Ⅰ. INTRODUCTION 9 relating implication The remaining of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents a review of the previous studies for understanding the pay inequality and the Korea industry. Section 3 explains and critiques the methodology of Theil s T statistic. Also there is description of the manufacturing data and variable definition. Section 4 shows results and we discuss and conclude in section 5 with suggestion for further research in this area.

Ⅱ. REVIEW OF THE LITERATURE 10 Ⅱ. REVIEW OF THE LITERATURE Although Kuznets hypothesized the effect of growth(or development) on inequality, later literature reversed this causal relationship. Empirical work seeking to confirm or reject Kuznets hypothesis has proliferated in recent years, using both pooled and panel data in attempt to shed light on the relationship across countries and time. The majority of this empirical work found a consistent, negative relationship between inequality and growth, typically based on multivariate cross-country regression models in which inequality is one variable determining growth. Birdsall, Ross and Sabot (1995), for example, found that egalitarianism was a key ingredient in the recipe for rapid growth in East Asia. Surveying twenty-three different studies, Benabou(1996) concluded that initial inequality is detrimental to long-run growth. In 1998 Klaus Deininger and Lyn Squire disrupted the emerging consensus with a study based on their ambitious new global inequality data set compiled for the World Bank from disparate household surveys of 108 countries since 1950.4 Based on the new data, Deininger and Squire (1998) found no evidence for Kuznets inverted U. Using the same data and panel specification, Forbes (2000) found that initial inequality leads to higher subsequent rates of growth. Several authors pointed out severe problems with the new data, however, casting a shadow over conclusions drawn from it.5 Galbraith and Kum(2002) show how problems with the Deininger and Squire data lead to multiple and contradictory conclusions about the

Ⅱ. REVIEW OF THE LITERATURE 11 relationship between inequality and growth(ranging from upright U to inverted U to positive linear and negative linear). Thus the negative relationship for most countries appears to remain intact, questions regarding causality and endogeneity notwithstanding. The efficiency wage theory argues that paying a wage premium may be profitable for firms because high wages can reduce monitoring costs, discourage turnover, attract a higher quality pool of applicants, and foster employee loyalty. Hence, wage dispersion across firms is observed when firms differ in their ability to monitor or motivate their workers, to bear the cost of turnover, or to measure labor quality. The theory of insider controls provides another institutional explanation for demand-related wage variation. If firms have product market power and their workers can bargain for a share of the rents, cross-firm differences in rents or in workers ability to extract rents generate wage differentials between firms. Although efficiency wage and insider theories explain why wages may be set above their market-clearing levels, their predictions for the impact of a wage premium on firm performance differ. Efficiency wages are compatible with profit maximization because they are intended to increase labor productivity. However, rent-seeking activities of insiders undermine the financial performance of the enterprise because these activities have no effect on worker performance. These competing theories of between-firm wage dispersion have been tested empirically but the extent to which wage dispersion is attributable to competitive versus noncompetitive factors remains unresolved. But we just look the tendency of inequality in Korea between 1993 and 2003. Comparing with sectors and regions gives many implications to Korea industry policy. The issues of efficiency wage policy will be discussing in further study.

Ⅱ. REVIEW OF THE LITERATURE 12 There has been large volume of studies on pay distribution in Korea since late 1970s. Although estimates of pay inequality slightly different depending upon the data used, most studies agree that pay inequality increases in 1990s, especially after the financial crisis 3) wealth is far less equally distributed than pay (Lee & Hwang, 1998; Lee, 2000). There is no consensus on the direction of pay inequality over the path of economic growth: rising inequality (Kim & Ahn, 1987); inverse-u type (Choo, 1993); falling inequality (Kim & Topel, 1995; Fields & Yoo, 2000). Despite the controversy over the direction of pay inequality, it is believed that factors such as education, industry, occupation, and experience, are important factors in determining the level of inequality over time. Since a financial crisis, certain institutions expressing the interests of the enterprises such as the Federation of Korean Industries ask further flexibility of labor market(federation of Korean Industries, 2000), it is doubtful whether its argument would be appropriate for the Korean economy, where job mobility has been quite restricted compared with most of developed economies. Regarding pay inequalities, Stiglitz(1999) admits that: pay inequality tends to rise in periods of economic crises, structural adjustment and output contractions. Although all available measures show widened pay inequalities during 1997 1999(Yoo and Kim, 2002) due to the increase in the number of the irregular workers and the unemployment rate, interpretations on the situation of pay inequalities since 2000 appear to depend on the survey methods. For instance, a measure such as the Gini coefficient based on urban workers households shows that the Gini coefficient increased from 0.307 in 1996 and 0.296 in 1997 to 3) Lee(2000), using the Family Income and Expenditure Survey reports the Gini coefficient for 1997(0.261) and for 1999(0.286).

Ⅱ. REVIEW OF THE LITERATURE 13 0.311 in 1999, but decreased to 0.301 0.303 in 2000 and 2001, presumably due to the increased public transfer and decreased unemployment rate; meanwhile, most other measures indicate that the Gini coefficient has been more or less stable since 1999(Park et al., 2002; Yoo and Kim, 2002). Most of previous research, however, mainly focuses on pay inequality at a point of time measured by inequality indices. Although this snapshot view of pay inequality receives attention from the public, it tells us little about the nature and the direction of pay inequality. Different from the previous studies, this paper attempts to analyze pay inequality by using Theil s T statistics through comparing with several between and within units. First of all, this paper looks the tendency of pay inequality with economic growth between 1993 and 2003. Second, we divide business sectors, locations and firm size etc, al. then find difference and characteristic. Finally, the effects of firm dynamics on pay inequality will be analysis in this paper.

Ⅲ. METHODOLOGY AND DATA 14 Ⅲ. METHODOLOGY AND DATA Theil s T statistic provides a useful alternative approach to measuring the change in earnings inequality within a single country, and to comparing degrees of change across countries. Theil s T statistic relies not on surveys, but on the regularly gathered official measures of income by region and sector. This method is to compute the between-groups component of Theil s T statistic across province-sector cells for both locations and business sectors. Theil s T is a very simple measure of inequality, relying only on two bits of information about each cell: its weight in total population(or employment), and the ratio of average income within the cell to average income in the country as a whole. The following formulae give the algebra behind Theil s T statisti c 4). While these particular equations use income as the variable of interest, Theil s T can address any number of qualifiable phenomena. When household data is available, Theil s T statistic is: n 1 y * p y *ln p T = p= 1 n μ y μ y (1) where is the number of individuals in the population, is the income of the person indexed by, and is the population s 4) Equations (1), (2), and (3)closely follow: Pedro Conceição, James K. Galbraith, and Peter Bradford; The Theil Index in Sequences of Nested and Hierarchic Grouping Structures: Implications for the Measurement of Inequality through Time, with Data Aggregated at Different Levels of Industrial Classification, Eastern Economic Journal, Volume 27 (2000), Pages 61 74.

Ⅲ. METHODOLOGY AND DATA 15 average income. If every individual has exactly the same income, T will be zero; this represents perfect equality and is the minimum value of Theil s T. If one individual has all of the income, T will equal ln n this represents utmost inequality and is the maximum value of Theil s T statistic. If members of a population can be classified into mutually exclusive and completely exhaustive groups, then Theil s T statistic is made up of two components, the between group element ( ) and the within group element ( ). ' w T = Tg + T g (2) When aggregated data is available instead of individual data, can be used as a lower bound for the population s value of Theil s T statistic. The between group element of Theil s T can be written as: m pi yi yi T ' g = * *ln i= 1 P μ μ (3) where indexes the groups, is the population of group, is the total population, is the average income in group, and is the average income across the entire population. is bounded above by, the natural logarithm of the total population divided by the size of the smallest group. This value is attained when the smallest group holds all the resource. When data is hierarchically nested (i.e. every municipality is in a province and each province is in a country) Theil s T statistic must increase or stay the same as the level of aggregation becomes (i.e. ). Theil s T statistic for the population equals

Ⅲ. METHODOLOGY AND DATA 16 the limit of the between group Theil component as the number of groups approaches the size of the population. Theil s T has properties that make it attractive for this type of calculation; in particular it is possible to sum row and column elements so as to arrive at cross-sector and cross-province measures of inequality. It is also possible to look directly at the contribution to overall inequality of each cell, sector or province, and to gauge the change in that contribution from year to year. Of course, the general comparison of the Theil index methodology is made by estimating pay inequality for individual person between countries or regions. In the current study, we however compare the pay inequality for each firm between regions as well as sectors by applying Theil T statistic to firm level. Dong (2005)analyzed wage inequality and between-firm age in the 1990 s employing the Theil methodology, where data of rural and urban firms were used. Galbraith (2004) evaluated pay inequality of 1979 through 1998 in the Indian manufacturing sector and inequality. Hence, we examine the pay inequality of the Korean manufacturing industry according to sector, region, and firm size with firm level data of 1993 to 2003. The data used in this study was the unpublished plant-level data assembled from the Annual Report on Mining and Manufacturing Survey in Korea. The data covers all plants with five or more employees in 580 manufacturing industries at the KSIC(Korean Standard Industrial Classification) five-digit level. It was an unbalanced panel data with about 76,341 to 103,126 observations for each year from 1993 to 2003. In the survey data, the entry and exit of plants were identified based on the plants appearing and disappearing over time. Entry and exit of plants due to spin-off, split, merger, and acquisition could not

Ⅲ. METHODOLOGY AND DATA 17 be identified with the available plant level data base. During the analysis period, a total of 300,916 distinct plants were observed. As such, the data contains entering, exiting and surviving plants. The data are available at the five-digit industrial classification level for All Korea manufacturing industry The total number of observations was 1,030,643. Plants that had more than 300 employees were denoted as firm 5. When the numbers of employees were between 300 and 100, the plants were classified as firm 4. And firm 3 has employees from 50 to 100, firm 2 has less than 50 and more than 20. The last part is firm 5. The annual changes in the number of firms, the aggregated firm characteristics and the number of employees for each group were described here.

Ⅲ. METHODOLOGY AND DATA 18 Table 2. A descriptive statistics of firms between 1993-2003 Year Observations Variables Mean St.D Sum Numbers worker 31.779 208.754 2724481 85731 1993 85731 cost 379.248 4220.84 32513353.97 85731 income 8.631 3.595 739980.13 85731 worker 31.307 219.119 2765299 88328 1994 88328 cost 423.511 5402.72 37407942.77 88328 income 9.687 3.995 855685.85 88328 worker 30.188 220.483 2815581 93267 1995 93267 cost 466.228 5763.59 43483779.06 93267 income 10.9889 4.712 1024908.73 93267 worker 29.386 231.493 2763178 94030 1996 94030 cost 502.276 6389.42 47229078.07 94030 income 12.264 5.202 1153255.23 94030 worker 27.673 207.738 2462853 88996 1997 88996 cost 519.288 6006.66 46214574.74 88996 income 13.203 5.980 1175073.3 88996 worker 27.789 191.076 2121474 76341 1998 76341 cost 511.083 6203.56 39016613.39 76341 income 12.736 6.174 972350.86 76341 worker 26.653 181.815 2349268 88140 1999 88140 cost 506.890 6325.64 44677291.12 88140 income 13.240 6.260 1167057.76 88140 worker 26.360 182.188 2513212 95341 2000 95341 cost 554.165 6956.6 52834698.78 95341 income 14.468 6.902 1379404.56 95341 worker 24.267 150.815 2502568 103126 2001 103126 cost 549.812 6609.62 56699976.95 103126 income 15.834 7.591 1632992.26 103126 worker 23.643 142.690 2540690 107459 2002 107459 cost 585.830 6835.44 62952772.28 107459 income 17.412 8.467 1871169.21 107459 worker 23.550 146.996 2587851 109884 2003 109884 cost 618.989 7598.76 68017010.54 109884 income 18.463 9.097 2028859.24 109884

Ⅳ. RESULTS 19 Ⅳ. RESULTS First of all, we look the tendency of pay inequality with economic growth between 1993 and 2003. We begin by examining the information in the KSIC data at the five-digit classification level, for Korea as a whole. Fig. 3 presents the Theil statistic resulting from this exercise. Fig. 3. Pay Inequality of Korean Manufacturing. 1993-2003 We find out the inequality trend that Theil value remained stable and consistent in the early 90's. and that it was slightly on the decline. However We observe that the graph shows a sharp upswing in the year 1993-2003, remains fairly steady till 1993-96, then jump up rapidly in 1996-98. Thereafter inequality in manufacturing pay remained steady till the year 1999-2003, at which point it began creeping upward. This is definitely different from the augmented Kuznets Curve that ineqaulity increases with an increase in economic levels as found in the US, Japan, and UK. The Korean economy

Ⅳ. RESULTS 20 didn't reach up to the economic level of developed countries but we just reformed and maintained the economy. Hence, if the economy had been stabilized and reformed properly, the inequality should have become similar to the one before or decreased stably. However, as seen in Fig. 2, the ineqaulity increase drastically after a financial crisis. The radical economic reform for too short time period does not result in concurrence of economic growth and inequality but more increased inquality than economic growth. Therefore, this type of reform will be expected to cause some problems stated above. So, based on political consideration of these facts, we have to think over wag distribution and economic development plans. To further examine whether inequality in Korea is primarily a geographic or a location issue, we aggregate the location-sector elements into two distinct categories, locations on the one hand and sectors on the other. The two digit industrial classification available at the location level is similar to the three digit classification available at the national level. The data are available for sixteen categories across 5 major states for this period. As explained above, we have inequality across sectors within states, inequality across locations, inequality across locations within sectors and inequality across sectors. Through this trend of Theil values, we find that in this data inequality has been steadily increasing since 1996 when the Korean economy faced financial crises, and that in the 2000s pay inequality has continued to increase, taking a sharp jump in the final year observed to levels higher than in the early 1990s. Thus the pattern suggests that the regional element of inequality in Korea started to rise before purely sectoral increases became pronounced and also before the major economic reforms. The next issue we examine is which of the specific regions

Ⅳ. RESULTS 21 and sectors have contributed the most to rising inequality. We first examine the contribution to Theil index of individual states. Fig. 4 and 5 presents this information. Fig. 4. The Contribution of Firm sizes to Pay Inequality in Korea Fig. 4 shows the contribution of firm size to pay inequality in Korea. Firm sizes divided by the number of employees. There are total five firm sizes and the standards of firm s employees are 5, 30, 50, 100 and 300. Firm sizes whose pay rates exceed the average form elements above the zero line, while states with pay rates below the national average form elements below the zero line. The size of the component attributable to each region and firm sizes represent the combined influence of labor force and relative income, and it is the change in these influences which the figure highlights. The firms are ranked by the size of their contribution to interstate inequality in the first year under observation. Through this figure we can find that the pay inequality of small size rapidly increased since 1998. This result related with the industrial policies for firms with different-sized classes changed dramatically, in the post-crisis period. As a result of the recovery

Ⅳ. RESULTS 22 policy, LSEs succeeded in necessary downsizing during the immediate aftermath of the fiscal crisis and to grow rapidly in the post-crisis period, especially in the export market. In the case of LSEs, its portion does not change even if the overall equality increases. On the other hand, the portion of SMEs increases with an increase in the entire inequality. It is shown that SMEs takes an amount of the position. Nevertheless, the fact that the portion has increased since 1997 indicates that SMEs were still suffering from the effects of the recession especially in the domestic market. Fig. 5 shows the contribution of firm s regions to pay inequality in Korea. Locations divided 5 areas. There are nearby Seoul, Kyungsang, Julra, Chungchong and rest areas. Area 1 makes the largest contribution to inequality during the entire period. This should not come as a surprise as it is the most advanced industrial area in Korea all the leading industrial houses have established manufacturing facilities in the Korea. Labor in Area1 is also highly organized; therefore almost all industrial groups in Area 1 have pay-rates above the All-Korea average. Fig. 5. The Contribution of Individual locations to Pay Inequality in Korea

Ⅳ. RESULTS 23 On examining the negative Theil elements we find that two of the Areas have rapidly changes. Pay rates of Area 2 and Area 5 below the national averages in some period. This could be primarily due to the lack of large enterprises from either the public or private sectors in these two states. Most of the industrial establishments in these areas are quite small and belong to such traditional sectors as food processing. Finally, most of the smaller states make either no contribution or make a small negative contribution to the Theil index. The smallness of their contribution in absolute value is an artifact of their small weight in overall manufacturing employment in Korea. Fig. 6. The Evolution of Inequality across Manufacturing Sectors The increase in Theil index from 1997 is primarily due to an increase in the Theil element of generation of electrical energy, distribution of electrical energy, manufacture of computers and computer based systems, manufacture of general purpose non electrical machinery and manufacture of motor cars.

Ⅳ. RESULTS 24 All of these got a boost after the liberalization of policies regarding production capacities and industrial licensing. We infer from this evidence that one effect of the reforms was to strengthen the market position of those sectors which were already comparatively strong, and so to increase the dispersion of manufacturing pay across Korea as a whole since Asia Crisis. The figure shows the firm s distribution of 2-digit enterprises like basic metal industries, rubber, plastic, petroleum and coal, and electricity generation & distribution, as well as the large-scale modern enterprises in chemicals, transport equipment, and machinery and equipment (both groups 35 & 36). These are the major winners and contributors to the inequality of manufacturing sector incomes. Sectors like digit 32 and 20 manufacturing are the long-standing losers. Of particular interest is the increasing contribution of the Theil element in the electricity sector over the years, particularly as the sector has become deregulated and increasingly able to assert its monopoly power. Indeed the rise of the power of the power sector is the single largest and perhaps the only significant contributor to the rise of intersectoral inequality in Korean manufacturing under the rule of reform.

Ⅴ. DISCUSSION 25 Ⅴ. DISCUSSION Using data sets 1993-2003, this paper analyzes income inequality in Korea. By Theil T statistics, it is shown that overall income inequality increased and the persistent component dominantly shapes income inequality. The result shows some patterns of pay inequality between locations and firm sizes. We can safely conclude that inequality in Korea manufacturing sector wages have increased since the 1996: both all-korea and locations measures agree on this point. Korea manufacturing however retains many of the characteristics of a planned and a dual economy, with a strong influence of the firm structure and on relative wages. In this paper, we can find a positive and significant relationship between firm pay inequality and size, region, R&D, export, diversification and business sectors, even when we controlling for individual, time period and firm characteristics. The decomposability property of Theil index enables us to show that manufacturing pay inequality in Korea has risen both across sectors and across regions, though more strongly across sectors. We also show that the rise in inequality accelerates in the period following the introduction of reforms, after controlling for changes in the level of real per capita income. It appears that a large part of rising manufacturing pay inequality in the post-reform period can be attributed to rising relative pay in the electricity sector. The differential region of these industries in the different states contributes strongly to the patterns of inequality between regions. Thus even industrially backward regions have manufacturing wages

Ⅴ. DISCUSSION 26 above the national average, due to the presence of large-scale public sector undertakings within their boundaries. Although certain parts of Korea are very much richer than others, Korea does not show a pattern of rising regional inequality in the last decades in this data. Instead, the rise in inequality appears at least within the manufacturing sector to be a phenomenon of rising relative incomes in sectors with power, and particularly in the utility and especially the electricity sectors. Overall, though, inequality has been increasing in manufacturing pay since the 1996, with particular increases since the formal beginning of the reforms. This increase cannot be accounted for strictly by increasing average incomes, as the rise in inequality persists even when changes in average income between regions is fully controlled for. In further study, we will investigate the firm dynamics with pay inequality in the same period and find the effect of firms characteristics according to R&D, export and organization of firms.

Reference 27 Reference Abowd, John M., Kramarz, Francis, Margolis, David, 1999. High wage workers and high wage firms. Econometrica 67, 251 333. Amsden, A., 1989. Asia s Next Giant: South Korea and Late Industrialisation. Oxford University Press, Oxford. Bénabou, R., 1996. Inequality and Growth," in Bernanke, B. and J. Rotemberg, eds., NBER Macro Annual 1996, MIT Press: Cambridge, MA: 11-76. Choo, Hak Chung, 1993. Income Distribution and Distributive Equity in Korea, in L.B. Krause and F.K. Park edited Social Issues in Korea: Korean and American Perspective, Korea Development Institute. Conceição, Pedro and Galbraith, James K., 2001.Toward an Augmented Kuznets Hypothesis, in James K. Galbraith and Maureen Berner, eds., Inequality and Industrial Change: A Global View, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press. Crotty, J., Lee, K.-K., 2002. A politico-economic analysis of the failure of neo-liberal restructuring in post-crisis Korea. Dong, Xiao-Yuan, 2005. Wage inequality and between-firm wage dispersion in the 1990s: A comparison of rural and urban enterprises in China Journal of Comparative Economics 33 (2005) 664 687. Fields, Gary and Yoo Gyeongjoon, 2000. Falling Labor Income Inequality in Korea s Economic Growth: Patters and Underlying Causes, Review of Income and Wealth, Volume 46, No.2. Federation of Korean Industries. 2002. Policy Proposals, October 10, 2000 and September 9. Feldstein, M. 1998. Refocusing the IMF, Foreign Affirs, (March/April), 20-33. Fischer, S. 1998. The IMF and Asian Crisis, (March 20). Government of Korea. Letter of Intent, 1997. 3 Decembre 1997 and 24 Decembre 1997. Henri Theil, 1972. Statistical Decomposition Analysis: With Applications in the Social and Administrative Sciences, Amsterdam-London: North Holland

Reference 28 Publishing Company. James K,.William A. Darity, Jr., Lu Jiaqing, 1998. Measuring the Evolution of Inequality in the Global Economy, International Capital Markets and the Future of Economic Policy Working Paper No. 4 James K.Galbraith, 2004, Pay Inequality in the Indian Manufacturing Sector, 1979-1998, University of Texas Inequality Project Working Paper No. 28 Kang, Byung-Goo., Yun, Myeong-Su., 2003. Changes in Korean Wage Inequality 1980 2000. Kim, Dae Mo and Ahn, Kuk Shin,1987. The determinants and perception of Income Distribution in Korea. Mimeo. Kim, Dae il and Topel Robert, 1995. Labor Markets and Economic Growth: Lessons from Korea s Industrialization, 1970-1990 in Difference and Changes in Wage Structures edited by Richard Freeman and Lawrence Katz. National Bureau of Economic Research Comparative Labor Market Series. University of Chicago Press. Kim, Yong-Seong, 2004. Short-run versus Long-run Income Inequality, Unpublished. Kwack, Sung Yeung, 1998. Factors Contributing to the Financial Crisis in Korea, Journal of Asian Economics, Volume. 9, 611-625. Kuznets, Simon, 1955. Economic Growth and Income Inequality, American Economic Review, 45, 1-28. Lee, Joung-woo and Hwang, Seong-hyeon 1998. The Problems of Income Distribution and Related Policy Issues in Korea, The KDI Journal of Economic Policy Volume. 20. No. 1.2. Lee, Woo sung. 2000. Unequal Asset ownership and increasing income inequality Weekly Economy. Volume. 594, LG Economic Research Institute. Mah, Jai S., 2006. Economic restructuring in post-crisis Korea, The Journal of Socio-Economics 2006 article in press. Oh, Inha., Heshmati, Almas., Baek,Chulwoo., Lee, Jeong-Dong Lee., 2005. Comparative Analysis of Firm Dynamics by Size: The Korean Manufacturing. TEP Discussion Paper No. 2005-1 Okun, Arthur, 1975. Equality and Efficiency: The Big Tradeoff. Washington: The Brookings Institution. Park, C., Kang, S.-H., Kim, T., 2002. Income inequality and poverty level in

Reference 29 Korea. KIHASA Working Paper, Seoul. Pedro Conceição, James K. Galbraith, and Peter Bradford, 2000. The Theil Index in Sequences of Nested and Hierarchic Grouping Structures: Implications for the Measurement of Inequality through Time, with Data Aggregated at Different Levels of Industrial Classification, Eastern Economic Journal, Volume 27, Pages 61 74. Postel-vinay, Fabien, Robin, Jean-Marc, 2002. Equilibrium wage dispersion with worker and employer heterogeneity. Econometrica 70, 2295 2350. World Bank, 1993. The East Asian Miracle: Economic Growth and Public Policy. Oxford University Press, New York. Yoo, K.-J., Kim, D.-I., 2002. Structural change in income distribution since the foreign exchange crisis and the impact of the redistribution policy. KDI Working Paper, Seoul. Yoshitomi, M., 2003. Post-Crisis Development Paradigms in Asia, Asian Development Bank Institute, Tokyo.

SUMMARY 30 SUMMARY [Title] Analysis of Pay Inequality and its Impacts on Growth, and Performance in Korean Industry ㆍ Project Leader: Yunhee Kim Abstract This paper examines the relationship among pay inequality, economic growth and innovation in Korea. So we estimated pay inequality in Korea s manufacturing sector using panel-level data for the period 1993 to 2003. The objective is to estimate pay inequality by using Theil s index and to identify the factors determining pay inequality and find the relationship with economic growth and innovation. We first review changes in industrial trend, production, and investment patterns over the period and how those changes led to the creation of a relatively pay inequality between and within regions and sectors. We then compare annual changes in manufacturing pay inequality and annual GDP growth, finding that the previously stable, negative relationship predicted by Kuznets broke down at the height of the period of structural reform in Korea, giving way to a positive relationship after 1998. On the basis of Theil s T statistics, results shows a positive relationship between firms pay inequality and size, location, R&D intensity, export, diversification and business sectors. The relation holds even when we control individual, time period and firm characteristics. The decom-posability property of the Theil index enables us to show that manufacturing pay

SUMMARY 31 inequality in Korea has risen both across sectors and regions, though more strongly across industrial sectors. Despite controlling for changes in the level of real per capita income, the rise in inequality accelerates in the period following the introduction of reforms. It appears that a large part of rising pay inequality can be attributed to rising relative pay in the ICT sector. The findings support the hypothesis of an augmented Kuznets Curve according to which some developed countries are found on an upward-sloping addendum to Kuznets original formulation. Keywords: Pay Inequality, Korea, Financial Crisis, Kuznets curve, innovation

저자 ㆍ김윤희ㅣ서울대학교ㅣ : : 정책자료 2007-10 한국산업의지역별소득불균형분석과산업의성장및성과에대한영향력연구 2007년 9월일인쇄 2007년 9월일발행 著者ㅣ김윤희發行人ㅣ정성철發行處ㅣ과학기술정책연구원서울특별시동작구보라매길 44( 신대방동 395-70) 전문건설회관 26층 Tel: 02)3284-1800 FAX: 02)849-8016 登錄ㅣ 2003년 9월 5일제20-444호組版및印刷ㅣ레드씨 Tel: 02)2278-6050 FAX: 02)2268-4087